Showing posts with label planning. Show all posts
Showing posts with label planning. Show all posts

Friday, May 24, 2019

Urban Libertarianism

Planning is generally thought as being centralized, command and control. Maybe once upon a time? Central planning makes sense when an economy can be directed toward a single goal: winning a war, engaging in 'catch-up' economic development. But when neither the way forward nor the common goals is known, central planning is problematic: You can't plan for something without a common understanding of ways and means, what is to be achieved, and how. 

As an urban planner, I am somewhat bemused by my own libertarianism. Perhaps a function of living in a blue city in a red state: I get why red states rail against the federal government in a very visceral way: top down intervention by a bunch of buffoons who either don't care about local context, or are hostile to it. 

So, let me define 'urban libertarianism' as the following: The most minimal restrictions on liberty possible, consistent with public safety, health, welfare, and morals. Or, as the Wiccan's put it: "An Ye Harm None, Do What Ye Will". But in a planning context, the harms (potentials for harm, endangerment) that must be considered are much broader, and longer lasting than in personal interactions. 

In an urban context, 'harming none' a pretty high standard. Unlike the country, there is simply less margin for error in a city: Things are closer together. So when you fire a gun, drive a car, build a structure, there are more limitations on where you can do it, when, and how.   This seems like common sense to me. When I go shooting, I recognize that I need to go someplace there is no-one to hit, and that what I'm shooting at should be back-stopped by a hill. And I recognize that there is a difference in building a shed by backyard, and building a house on a hill (which might slide downhill onto someone else's house). 

The importance of public safety is the easiest one to elucidate. Health likewise: noxious land uses are limited in where they are permitted to locate, recognizing proximity to many industrial pollutants is sickening. Welfare...let us take a moment to define it: the good fortune, health, happiness, prosperity, etc., of a person, group, or organization. (And ignore the spurious definition of 'a government handout'.) 

Welfare is more than the silver rule ("Do not do unto others as you would not have them do unto you"). The idea of public welfare relies more on an understanding of equity: You should not, in pursuit of your enjoyment, be permitted to make me miserable.  Even if you find that an acceptable trade-off. My classic example would be amplified music: Your neighbor feels it acceptable to impose it on you, with the (reasonable) expectation that you might expect to do the same. Within planning law, 'spite fences' would be the example: You cannot build a fence to block a view, with the aim of making me miserable, regardless of how much you might enjoy it.

'Morals' is something I would not have included five years ago, and indeed would have actively excluded. Perhaps becoming a parent has taught me how much of our civilization consists of customs and habits, prone to lapse, unless we are active in their transmission and perpetuation. In which case, what restrictions on human liberty in pursuit of public morality are acceptable to planning, in it's role as regulator of the built environment? You can't legislate morality: you can only legislate the creation of a built environment consistent with morality, one that facilitates moral behavior in public. Largely, it becomes a matter of how it's proper to act: specifically in the division of actions which are acceptable in the public realm, and those which ought be constrained to the private. And providing facilities accordingly: People don't defecate in the streets for kicks (looking at you, San Francisco). Paris doesn't provide public toilets out of generosity, but out of a recognition that if your built environment doesn't permit moral behavior, violations result. Crosswalks might be another example: Too many cities make it too difficult to cross the street legally. Likewise, too many cities make it too easy to speed--they encourage it even, designing streets as if they were rural highways.

Undeniably, restricting behavior for guard public safety, health, welfare, and morals leads to a parcel of restriction. But those restrictions ought be as minimal as possible, drawn as tightly as possible: the most minimal restrictions on liberty possible. And that requires laws drawn narrowly, even to the point of absurdity. Laws against protesting, or making a 'public nuisance' are far too broadly drawn. It invites abuse.

Over-regulation is rife. Let the thicket be pruned, and anything inconsistent with public safety, health, welfare, and morals be removed.




Friday, December 14, 2012

UTA needs to plan more light rail

UTA needs to plan for some more light rail. It's like planning for arterials roads--it represents a key link in the transportation network. Think of it this way: Commuter Rail = Highway. Thus, without to connect to, a 'highway to nowhere'? Governance scale also relevant--Commuter rail is the MSA, light rail a County-level project, and street-car a city level project. However, for roads, the Feds pay for most of the highways, the state pays for the major roads (most arterials are 'state highways'), and only the smaller roads are actually handled by cities. On that analogy, there is actually no transit 'small' enough that a city can handle it.

Regardless, Salt Lake County has it's light rail, and Weber, Davis and Utah all have commuter rail now. But UTA wants to build something--they've developed the capacity, and well, 'when you've got a hammer, everything starts looking like a nail'. I'm unpersuaded about the value of streetcars (however awesome Portland's has been), but still devoted to light rail and it's capacity for doing the things a bus can't do.

Saturday, June 16, 2012

Bus vs. Trains

I was reading Human Transit today, and thinking about the rail map. SLC has a similarly complex bus system. Why is not possible to have a similar map? Jared Walker has the right of it when he says 'many transit services that are stuck in mixed traffic'. This is the fundamental divide--not bus vs. train, but dedicated right of way vs. mixed traffic. Trains, being heavier and slower to stop, frequently get their own. Buses do not, and that makes all the difference.  Effective BRT means dedicated right of way


Wednesday, April 25, 2012

Neighborhoods & Amenity


In abstract, a house can be understood as a bundle of characteristics that determine its value. The value of a house is not determined solely by the characteristics of the house, but also by its location. These characteristics represent sources of amenity. Two broad classes of amenity exist: Amenity of structure and amenity of location. Structural amenities are typically defined by number of bedrooms, number of bathrooms, square footage, and other characteristics of the house. Amenities of location are typically characterized in terms of proximity to sources of amenity (shopping, recreation) and dis-amenity (air pollution, crime, noise). 

The importance of location is widely recognized in real-estate. All property occupies a unique location in space, and thus all real estate is unique and non-replicable. Nearby locations sharing similar characteristics often act as complements.

But there exists an additional package of amenities of location not contingent on proximity, typically characterized in terms of ‘neighborhood’. The concept is poorly defined, formally referring to a geographic area, but also referring to a less well articulated set of aspects associated with that that. Neighborhood membership is typically defined by proximity, but the boundaries of neighborhoods are rarely well defined, and may change over time.  

Neighborhoods are important because geographic proximity implies more frequent interaction. Whether interaction represents an opportunity or threat depends on the compatibility of residents. Does not imply social conformity, but rather social compatible—norms about the use of space, social presentation, privacy, and behavior do not conflict. Desirable neighborhoods are characterized by compatible socio-demographic groups. ‘Areas in transition’ represent shifts in the socio-demographic characteristics of a neighborhood, as different groups move and in and out.

Houses in a similar neighborhood already share amenities of proximity and amenities of neighborhood, so that neighborhoods with houses with similar amenities of structure also show highly uniform prices. This affects housing affordability, and results in a strong association in socio-economic status with neighborhood.